The Disintegration Of International Finance And Trade

Print   

02 Nov 2017

Disclaimer:
This essay has been written and submitted by students and is not an example of our work. Please click this link to view samples of our professional work witten by our professional essay writers. Any opinions, findings, conclusions or recommendations expressed in this material are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of EssayCompany.

INTRODUCTION:

Considering the period during 1930s, is is a fact that Germany played a major role in the disintegration of international finance and trade. This it was mainly due to the pressure of the history behind account deficits and controlled by the ideology which aimed to establish hegemony over Europe.

Also, some researchers have proved that Germany was the largest trading partner of the smaller European countries and transformed this in a theory of monopoly power in international trade. This together with the supposition that it abused the arrangements in order to benefit from resources of its partners generated a long living conception in this sense through time.From an alternative perspective, it was mentioned that all Germany`s efforts in political terms were not in its advantage from economic point of view. Moreover, by investing resources in order to build up its informal economic empire during the 1930s, according to existing literature it is a quantitative lack of evidence in order to prove that were sacrificed trade advantaged for political influence.

HYPOTHESIS:

This paper aims to employ that all the quantitative and qualitative evidence represents a re-examination of the hypothesis that Nazist trade before the Second World War exploited smaller European countries. As a fact, south-eastern Europe`s dependence on Germay was due to the collapse of these countries caused by their trade with the Soviet Union.

IMPORTANT FACTS:

The focus is primarily on the unpublished payments and foreign exchange balances from the records of Germany's ministry of commerce which survived in West Germany's national archive. These files include the aggregate balances of payments and of foreign exchange from 1936 to 1941 and a set of bilateral foreign exchange accounts with no less than 35 countries for the period from 1938 to 1940. This is precisely the time span for which the published sources provide only foreign trade statistics.The additional element covered by the unpublished material includes, first, the missing components of the balance of payments, such as transfers and capital movements, and second, the balances of foreign exchange outlays and receipts by country, broken down by balance-of­ payments categories and transactions on clearing account compared with convertible foreign exchange. Analysis of these data makes it possible to obtain a rich picture of the trade and payments flows of Nazi Germany before the Second World War. Examination of these and complementary sources on German foreign trade and exchange policies just before the outbreak of the Second World War lends support to the more recent contributions to the debate mentioned

above. The results suggest that foreign trade policy alone was not sufficient for Germany to establish the exploitation of the small. As a rule, exploitation appears to have begun only after the military occu­ pation of a given country, but then on a massive scale.

CONTENT TO BE CONSIDERED:

Section I introduces the conflicting basic hypotheses and measurement concepts.

Section II provides the summary data on foreign exchange balances for 1938-40 and calculates structural balance of payments deficits.

Section III surveys the cross-country evidence on Germany's balance of payments deficits as broken down by convertible cash and clearing account balances. By comparing net resource transfers on current account with cash transfers, an indication is obtained of the extent to which the system of bilateralized trade worked as an exploitation device.

Section IV turns to the depen­ dence of the smaller countries of central Europe on foreign trade with Germany. It is argued that most of this trade resulted from the loss of Russia as their main trading partner after the communist revolution.

Section V considers the regional patterns of Germany's international trade. It turns out that Germany's eastward trade offensive, which played such a prominent role in contemporary propaganda, is hard to detect in the data.

In Section VI the commodity structure of German wartime trade is examined briefly.

Section VII complements this with an intertemporal perspective to argue that German autarky policy in the 1930s was largely a selective retreat from financial relations with the western powers.

Section VIII concludes the details presented in the paper.

SECTION I

Three traditional views appear to have dominated the discussion on Nazi foreign trade policies. Most likely, none of these hypotheses has been put forward in the literature in the simplified fashion in which it is presented here. Nevertheless it seems that even the abridged theses to be sketched here cover a considerable part of what has been conventional wisdom on Nazi economic imperialism.

The first hypothesis maintains that bilateralism in German foreign trade policies served mostly as a device for exploiting smaller and weaker trade partners. The second suggests that in the course of a policy of economic penetration, Germany systematically reoriented its trade towards east central and south-eastern Europe. Under the heading of 'autarky policy', the third hypothesis cites Germany's import substitution policies in the

areas of fuel, rubber, and textiles as examples of a general withdrawal of Germany from its foreign trade relations. This article will attempt to reconsider and evaluate these hypotheses in the light of the records now available, supplemented occasionally by other foreign trade and national account data.

A conceptual difficulty in approaching the problem lies in the choice

of appropriate indicators. Child makes ample use of estimates of payment surpluses and deficits accruing to Germany, both on clearing account and in hard currency transactions. This is the main indicator used in section II. As a yardstick for the measurement of financial exploitation, this article follows Child in assuming that one obvious indicator of German 'strength' would be the net inflow of convertible cash reserves from a supposedly 'weak' country with which clearing accounts existed. In that case, Germany would have managed to attract cash reserves which in turn were needed to purchase scarce commodities from 'strong' countries that successfully refused to engage in trade on clearing account or even threatened to impose unilateral clearing on Germany in retaliation for its default on debt service. Likewise, exploitation in real terms will be examined in the light of Germany's ability to attract real resource transfers through the system of clearing accounts. In contrast to the case of cash surpluses, the structural indicator of strength on the part of Germany will now be a deficit. As clearing accounts established a system of trade credit, sustained deficits could be interpreted as a resource drain to Germany.

The concept used by Hirschman related to measures of market structure as an indicator of monopoly power. Hirschman focused his attention on dependence and preference in foreign trade as the main indicator of market structure; this concept will be employed and its implications re­examined further below.

SECTION II

Germany's aggregate balance of foreign exchange for 1938-41 is given in table 1. The accounts provide a breakdown of the various sources and uses of foreign exchange. Despite declining export revenues, surpluses persisted in commodity trade (1), whereas there were structural deficits in services (II)Y Following the accounting system then in use, interest payments were not included in services but are stated separately (III). The deficits in interest payments reflect only that portion of Germany's debt service that was effectively transferred, whether on clearing account or in convertible foreign exchange.

Table 2 shows the net inflow of foreign exchange on current account.

The compensating balance position is formed by net inflows of foreign exchange on credit account and changes in reserves. In the case of Nazi Germany, neither of these figures can be employed without qualification. In particular, the category 'Other capital flows' includes considerable foreign exchange revenues from sales of captured foreign assets. In 1938-9, the main entries were proceeds from trade in Austrian and Czechoslo­ vak gold reserves, whereas in 1940 the position included similar capital drains from France. Also, the net flows of foreign currency in cash, shown in table 2, still conceal information, as they include transactions in reichsmarks that left reserves unchanged. For the years 1938 to 1940, more detailed foreign exchange accounts are available from which the actual net balance of foreign exchange may be computed. Subtracting payments in reichsmarks and inflows from sales of captured assets, one arrives at the structural deficit in foreign exchange; its size varied between 0.3 and 1.1 billion RM per year (table 3).

To the initiated, tables 2 and 3 read almost like a chronicle of the main ruptures of Nazi foreign trade policies before Germany's fatal attack on Russia from mid-1941 onwards.During the first two years of Nazi rule, Germany was relatively successful in attracting fresh credit, despite repeated extensions of the 1931 standstill agreement on its short-term debt and the de facto default of 1933/4 on its long-term credit. One reason for this may have been Germany's selective repayment of debt, which discriminated against (mostly American) long-term debt in favour of continuing service on (mostly British) short-term trade credits. As a consequence, Germany's default was only a partial one, and short-term credits such as those negotiated in its clearing arrangements were still in good standing (table 4).

Indeed, as table 4 shows, much of the German deficit during the first years accrued on clearing account. This is probably the historical root of the exploitation hypothesis, as it was argued by Child and others that the clearing procedure was accepted only by 'weak' trading partners who could not prevent a real resource transfer to Nazi Germany. The validity of this hypothesis seems questionable for the early 1930s, when massive unemployment throughout Europe rendered the opportunity cost of additional exports to Germany very low. Lending to Germany on clearing account suddenly halted around 1935/6, precisely when many of these economies started to pick up. This was reflected within Germany by a severe foreign exchange crisis and political infighting over the priorities in the use of scarce foreign exchange. Generally, this crisis is seen as having triggered the four-year plan for intensified war preparation.

The subsequent years were marked by lack of any credit extensions to Germany, whereas in 1938 and 1939 the deficit was overcome by strong sales of Austrian and Czech reserves. Temporarily, the Anschluss of Austria in 1938 relieved Nazi Germany

of much of its resource scarcity, as Austria had been relatively rich in foreign reserves and assets. This helped the Germans to overcome their foreign exchange shortage for more than a year. Economically speaking, the annexation of Austria marked the beginning of Germany's policy of achieving economic growth on the extensive margin through military aggression.

C:\Users\Adina\Desktop\Untitled.png

Table 2. Net foreign exchange accrning on current account, 1938-1941 (RM

million)

1938 1939 1940 1941

a Unadjusted balance

(Table I, I + II + III)

-555

+295

-1,218

-3,793

less

b 'Political' transfers

-40

-62

-208

-1,702

c Other transfers remaining

Foreign exchange accruing

-18

-497

-17

+374

-18

-992

-18

-2,073

( +) on current account

Notes: row a: Unadjusted balance is sum of net results of I, II, and III in tab. I. Still inclusive of transfers; row b: 'Political' payments entry as shown in the records. Does not yet include all transfers received; row c: Grants and private transfers.

Source: see tab. I.

Table 3. Balance of payment surpluses in cash transactions, 1938-1941 (RM

million)

1938

1939

1940

1941

I Recorded cash surplus in foreign exchange balance

371

165

11

-22

less

II Incoming ( +) 'free RM'

309

182

-24

gives

III Addition ( +) to reserves

+62

-17

+2

less

IV Proceeds from selling spoils etc.

1,000

321

1,505

1,127

gives

V Actual BOP

-938

338

-1,125

(foreign exchange balance) surplus

Notes: row 1: from table 1. Includes cash payments in foreign exchange and in reichsmarks; row II: international cash payments in reichsmarks; row III: net foreign exchange income; row IV: 1938: mainly proceeds from Austrian reserves, 1939: mainly proceeds from Czech reserves, 1940: mainly proceeds from French reserves; row V: net foreign exchange income excluding sales of foreign reserves.

Sources: for row II and row IV, see tab. I.

Table 4. Gennan clearing debt, 1934-1944 (RM million)

1934

1935

1936

1937

1938

1939

1940

1941

1942

1943

1944

Stock

322

433

349

244

314

335

953

5,001

11,698

20,987

29,908

Flow

322

Ill

-84

-105

70

21

618

4,048

6,697

9,289

8,921

Sources: Deutsche Bundesbank, ed., Deutsches Geld- und Barkwesen, p. 41; German Federal Archives, R7/3636.

SECTION III

Data on the regional distribution of foreign exchange surpluses and deficits are available from 1938 both on clearing account and in cash. The first column of table 5 provides an overview of net inflows of foreign cash reserves by countries and regions in 1938. In that year the Reichsbank avoided insolvency only by selling off 1 billion RM net worth of Austrian foreign assets and reserves.

Group I of table 5 includes the Anglo-Saxon countries along with those British colonies available from the sample. With regard to the United States and Great Britain alone, net outflows of hard currency totalled 384 million RM in 1938; the deficit vis-a-vis-group I as a whole amounted to 0.5 billion RM. The second group comprises the countries of western and northern Europe which were later occupied by Nazi Germany; the deficit here is 170 million RM. Italy and the neutral states of Europe, on the one hand, and the countries of the Danube and the Balkans, on the other, are included in groups III and IV, respectively. A fifth group comprises Argentina, Brazil, and Chile, and a sixth includes Turkey, Iran, and the Far East.

As an indicator of German 'strength' table 5 uses the net inflow of convertible foreign exchange into Germany from a supposedly 'weak' country with which clearing accounts existed. In that case, Germany would attract cash reserves which were needed to purchase scarce com­ modities from 'strong' countries that successfully refused to trade on clearing account or even threatened to impose unilateral clearing. Looking at the figures for 1938 in this way, the striking result is that within Europe, only trade with Sweden yielded notable net revenues to Ger­ many/9 whereas the only surpluses to be noted overseas were with China and Japan. Germany thus appears to have been in the position of a rather 'weak' trading partner with regard to almost all countries in the sample.

The second column of table 5 repeats the exercise, this time on clearing

account. Here, a deficit would be an indicator of 'strength', revealing

Germany's ability to attract resources from abroad without really paying. Such deficits did indeed exist with respect to most European countries of the sample; only four cases show 'wrong' signs on the clearing account balance. However, this impression must be qualified when these results are compared with cash reserve balances. As a rule, large German deficits on clearing account seemed to be associated with similarly high deficits in cash.

This first attempt at structuring the evidence thus reveals ambiguous results. In this last peacetime year, Germany was not equally successful in imposing economic dominance on its trading partners within the clearing system. As a rule, clearing deficits were accepted by the creditor country only when backed by comparable cash outflows to the country in question. The extent to which the deviations from this rule can be explained is investigated below. The largest deficits in hard currency derived from trade with the victors of the First World War, for whose deliveries Germany had to pay in cash.

C:\Users\Adina\Desktop\Untitledjcjdcjd.png

C:\Users\Adina\Desktop\Untitled 1.png

In 1939, Germany's overall foreign exchange balance again shows structural deficits. It was only by sales of 321 million RM of foreign assets that the balance could be restored-and, due to the failure to capture all of Czechoslovakia's gold reserves, smaller amounts were available for sale than in 1938.

In cross-country comparison of cash reserve flows, most of the structures of 1938 appear to have persisted in 1939, albeit with changing shares, as shown by the entries for 1939 in table 5. In Europe, all the Scandinavian countries became net importers on a cash basis and thus created net foreign exchange income for Germany. The countries of the Danube basin continued to be a region of net outflows of German foreign exchange reserves. Trade with Asia again created surpluses, whereas, partly due to the blockade after the beginning of the war in September 1939, Germany's deficit with Latin America was considerably smaller than before. Marked changes, however, occurred in the figures relating to France and to the Anglo-Saxon countries. The deficit with regard to France diminished to some 30 per cent of its value in 1938, whereas for the Anglo-Saxon countries it disappeared almost entirely. Even taking into account that this trade was disrupted after Germany's attack on Poland in September 1939, this phenomenon of selective disengagement remains remarkable.

Looking at the clearing account balances for 1939, a marked structural shift emerges. The countries of group I which were later conquered by Germany, as well as the Asian and Latin American countries in the sample, all showed German clearing surpluses, and so did trade with the neutral states of Europe in group III. On the other hand, Italy and Hungary had to accept German clearing deficits again, whereas Yugoslavia reaped German surpluses. Note also the high German clearing deficit with Romania, which in 1938 was seen as a rather 'strong' trading partner but now fell back into the opposite role, being tied to Germany by the trade agreement of 23 March 1939.

If we look again at cash and clearing account transactions simul­ taneously, it appears that in 1939, the situation of 1938 was reversed in many cases. Some of the particularly 'weak' countries of 1938, i.e., Italy, Hungary, and Iran, remained in unfavourable positions, characterized by low cash revenues from and large credit extensions to Germany. Brazil now had German clearing surpluses and cash deficits, and hence was an extraordinarily 'strong' country. This is also true for the Netherlands, Switzerland, Yugoslavia, and, as before, Turkey. An example of the converse transition is given by Romania.

The general impression is again ambiguous. In continental Europe, Germany had clearing account deficits with only three countries but reaped surpluses in hard currency trade only from Scandinavia, having to supply foreign exchange cash to all other European countries. Germany thus appeared to be a rather 'weak' country with respect to its trade in continental Europe, although it was able to reduce substantially its foreign exchange deficits vis-a-vis the Anglo-Saxon world. Germany's disengage­ ment from its financial links with the victors of the First World War is the most noteworthy change in these data in 1939.

For 1940, conventional wisdom would predict massive changes in the regional distribution of Germany's payment flows.25 On the one hand, Germany's short-lived rise to continental hegemony may have had effects on its dominance over the neutral countries and those of south-eastern Europe. On the other hand, there may have been structural changes in trade with the now occupied countries of western and northern Europe, and it might be asked what was the net effect on the regional distribution of Germany's foreign trade. Judging from the cash balances, no such deep structural ruptures can be discerned, whether for the neutral countries, for those of the Danube basin, or for Italy. The only visible effect is an overall increase in deficits. Likewise, there seems to have been no dramatic effect on the Benelux states or on Norway and Denmark, all of which were by then under military occupation.

The dominant change was introduced by the inflow of almost 1.4 billion RM in foreign exchange from France. In the bilateral balance of foreign exchange with that country, a corresponding amount is given under the heading 'Other capital transactions'; the same amount reappears in Germany's aggregate foreign exchange balance of 1940. This is also the position where, in the balances of 1938 and 1939, the proceeds from selling off captured Austrian and Czechoslovakian reserves had been included. As Germany's foreign exchange balance for 1940 closed with a net surplus of only 11 million RM in cash, the entire amount of these new spoils must have been spent in the same year.

In contrast to cash flows, marked structural changes can be found in the clearing accounts for 1940. With Greece and Slovakia as the only exceptions, all states of southern and south-eastern Europe now exhibited German clearing account surpluses, which in the cases of Italy and Hungary were about large enough to make good the cumulative deficits of the two preceding years. The apparent losers on clearing account were the Benelux states. A remarkable clearing deficit existed vis-a-vis the USSR as well. Contrary to expectation, the weaker countries of the neutral zone and of southern and south-eastern Europe continued to be in a 'strong' bargaining position, characterized both by net foreign exchange revenues and by net credit extensions from Germany, as table 5 shows. Some losers of previous years even compensated for their previous losses. Germany's rise to military and economic hegemony thus entailed very different consequences for the occupied

SECTION IV

A second indicator of the impact of national power politics on foreign trade is the dependence of small countries on foreign trade with Germany, dependence that in many cases was considerable. The first row in table 6 shows the share of Greater Germany in the foreign trade of three such countries, Romania, Bulgaria, and Greece, in 1938.

At first sight, it is tempting to interpret the evidence shown in table 6 in accordance with conventional wisdom. For example, the Bulgarian case could be considered as evidence of an extreme degree of dependence created by the system of bilateralized trade. However, this approach appears to be misleading for two reasons. First, all of south-eastern Europe had lost its trade with Russia and been forced to redirect trade to countries in central and western Europe. Second, comparable degrees

of dependence already existed before the First World War. This latter effect becomes apparent when the corresponding evidence for 1913 is examined.

Table 6. Trade dependence on Germany in intertemporal comparison

Percentage shares in imports (M) and Bulgaria Romania Greece exports (X) of

(a) Share in total trade

M

X

M

X

M

X

Greater Germany, 1938

52.0

58.9

34.3

19.3

28.8

38.5

Germany and Czechoslovakia, 1938

57.9

63.5

46.5

27.6

Germany and Habsburg Monarchy, 1913

43.2

19.9

63.7

22.1

23.6

21.0

(b) Share in non-Russian trade

Germany and Habsburg Monarchy, 1913

50.5

24.8

65.1

22.2

29.4

21.6

Germany and Czechoslovakia, 1938

57.9

63.5

47.0

27.6

29.6

38.6

Source: Mitchell, European historical statistics.

To render these figures comparable with those of 1938, territorial changes have to be taken into account. After the annexation of 1938, Austria was included in German statistics as part of Greater Germany, whereas in 1913 it had been the centrepiece of the Habsburg empire, which also included Hungary and Czechoslovakia. The tables from which the figures are taken do not include Hungary among the main trading partners of any of the countries of the present sample in 1938. Hence there remains a weighting error when trade with Czechoslovakia is added to the dependence ratios of 1938 in order to capture trade with comparable regions. Inspection of these data nevertheless shows that results depend on how the standard of reference is set. What appears to be the impact of a giant German trade offensive in isolated comparison looks far less impressive when a suitable intertemporal perspective is adopted and the effects of prewar trade with Russia are eliminated. This leads to the second conclusion: that, judging from comparison with prewar figures, the extension of Nazi Germany's trade with the countries of south-eastern Europe appears to a large extent merely as a return to the position of dominance that the Habsburg monarchy and imperial Germany jointly had in the Balkans before the First World War. Additional dependence effects were created by Germany's filling of the gap left by Russia's isolation from east European markets under communist rule.

This result may be interpreted in different ways. It could be concluded, for instance, that a similar system of power politics already applied in the prewar period. Care should be taken not to overemphasize this point, as other factors, including locational advantages, may have played a role also. However, the fact that trade dependence on Germany-cum­ Austria was already massive before the First World War cannot be ignored either. Another interpretation would stress the loss of power-political equilibrium in eastern Europe as a result of the defeat of tsarist Russia in the First World War and the subsequent political and economic impotence of the USSR until well into the 1930s. Although this view helps to explain why filling the vacuum was so easy for fascist Germany, it ignores the rapidly growing military and economic strength of the USSR on the eve of the war. Indeed, the perception of the growing threat presented by the massing of Soviet troops near its borders appears to have brought about Romania's decision to create close ties with Nazi Germany in 1939.

In any case, the evidence shows that there is a precedent for depen­ dencies in foreign trade in south-eastern Europe. Thus, the economic penetration of that region by German trade was not simply a particular characteristic of Nazi policies, but a more complex phenomenon, in which the collapse of central European trade with Russia played a pivotal role.

SECTION IV

Reversing the focus of the previous section, we now tum to the role that central and south-east Europe played in the Nazi economy. The idea that there should be a role for Mitteleuropa in future German trade had been commonplace among advocates of a German retreat from world markets since the tum of the century. During the great depression, the agenda was revitalized, although with limited success.It later played a major part in Nazi economic propaganda. How successful was this doc­ trine economically when put into political practice? The search for an answer to this question starts by examining the regional distribution of Germany's foreign trade on the eve of the Second World War. The (now regionally aggregated) foreign exchange balances reveal a regional pattern of foreign exchange flows (table 7).

For 1938, there is a clear dominance of the Anglo-Saxon world and western Europe, which, however, diminished in 1939 through the reduction of Germany's deficits vis-a-vis the western powers. In the data for 1940 in table 5, the same effect was reflected in the large clearing account deficits in respect of western Europe and the very low deficits or even surpluses in central and eastern Europe. Looking again at the cumulative figures for 1944 given in table 5, this impression is recon­ firmed: the deficit with respect to France alone was almost as large as the whole deficit vis-a-vis eastern and south-eastern Europe, and of the total clearing debt of more than 30 billion RM, about two-thirds was with the countries that later formed the European Community.

Although no regional data on German wartime trade after 1940 are

accessible, such material as is available for 1940 does seem to support the hypothesis that Germany's war economy became more westward oriented: the share of western Europe in trade across German borders increased after 1938 instead of decreasing. But the trade statistics underly­ ing table 8 reflect real resource transfers only indirectly. If the clearing account balances of table 5 and the evidence on real occupation costs in the same table are considered instead of trade statistics, the share of western Europe is far higher than indicated by trade figures even in

1940. All this leads to a third conclusion, confirming a hypothesis of

Milward.35 The eastward move of Germany's economic interests under

the Nazi 'new order' is merely a chimera. In spite of all ideological commitment to the contrary, and in spite of the eastbound thrust of the Nazi war effort, the German war economy was in fact westward oriented.

Table 7. Gennan foreign exchange revenues and expenditures by country,

1938 (RM million)

Group I Group II

us

c

388.9

D

537.9

France

c

252.4

D

278.2

Britain

517.0

702.2

Netherlands

569.8

677.4

India

137.5

166.5

Denmark

218.8

207.7

Canada

29.2

64.4

Norway

146.1

150.8

Australia

22.1

29.2

Belgiwn/Luxembourg

262.8

335.6

S. Africa

91.8

92.0

Egypt

51.8

61.4

1,449.9

1,649.7

1,238.3

1,653.6

Group III

Group IV

c

D

c

D

Switzerland

236.9

282.9

Yugoslavia

153.6

179.4

Italy

372.4

400.1

Hungary

165.6

183.1

Finland

86.4

85.2

Romania

170.1

160.1

Sweden

294.3

227.8

489.3

522.6

990.0 996.0

Group V

Group VI

Argentina

c

183.0

D

223.7

Turkey

c

176.0

D

152.1

Brazil

205.7

213.6

Iran

38.4

49.9

Chile

73.1

97.0

China

105.7

88.1

461.8 534.3

Manchuria

53.7

74.3

Japan

156.6

48.9

530.3

413.3

Note: In the column headings, C stands for credit and D for debit.

Source: see tab. 5.

Table 8. The structure of Gennan foreign trade 1928-1960 (%)

(a) Commodity structure: share of

Agriculture Raw materials Semi-finished Finished

1928

M

40.9

X

6.4

M

28.3

X

12.2

M

17.9

X

12.2

M

12.9

X

69.2

1938

39.5

1.2

32.9

9.5

18.8

8.4

7.9

80.8

1940

47.2

2.5

21.0

14.8

21.2

9.3

9.7

73.4

1943

40.0

6.8

13.5

13.1

13.1

13.0

32.4

66.9

1950

44.1

2.3

29.6

14.0

13.7

18.8

12.6

64.9

1960

26.3

2.3

21.7

4.6

18.9

10.4

32.2

82.4

(b) Country strUcture: share of BEG

in European trade in total trade Total

100* (X-M2

1928

M

34.1

X

32.5

M

17.3

X

24.4

X+M

-7.4

1938

26.4

32.7

14.4

22.8

-1.8

1940

29.6

28.3

27.6

26.9

-1.5

1950

47.0

48.3

25.5

36.4

-13.6

1960

55.9

48.9

32.4

32.9

Note: totals for 1928 and 1950 do not include Saar district. In column headings, M stands for impons and X

for expons.

Sources: Statistisches Handbuch von Deutschland (1949); Statistisches Jahrbuch (1962)

SECTION VI

Turning to the commodity structure, intuition would imply that, in line with the Malthusian doctrines prevalent in Germany at the time, the Nazis used the occupied countries mainly to extract foodstuffs, natural resources, and raw materials. A structure of extreme specialization would be expected, which would also be consistent with Germany's previous trade history, as even before the Second World War, its imports consisted chiefly of primary goods. As table 8 shows, initially such a pattern is indeed visible: up to 1940, the Nazi economy pushed the traditional specialization pattern of the German economy to the extreme.

However, later in the war, this tendency was reversed dramatically,

and imports of finished goods became dominant in 1943. Thus, Ger­ many's import structure 'de-specialized' itself during the war. This is a remarkable phenomenon which has hitherto been neglected. Even under the auspices of Nazi dominance over Europe, the German trade structure under the 'new order' somehow anticipated the later tendency towards intra-industrial trade within Europe, which reappeared in West Germany's import accounts only during the mid-1950s. Not until 1960 did the share of finished commodities in German imports recover to the level of 1943 (table 8). It should be noted that no such anticipation of future structures was visible in German exports. Rather, they exhibited a deviation from a long-term trend that prevailed before the war and re-emerged later. However, surprising tendencies are visible even in the export data. Whereas the export structure of 1950 was similar to that of 1928, striking similarities seem to exist between the commodity structure of German exports in 1960 and in 1938.It is tempting to interpret this as a similar reconstruction gap, in which the trade data for 1950 appear like a relapse into outdated patterns that prevailed during the inter-war years and that indicated the potential for future reconstruction. This somewhat startling evidence corroborates the data on regional specialization and leads us to a fourth conclusion: the German orientation towards intra-industrial trade within western Europe appears to have its origins in the Second World War. Both the regional and commodity structures of trade flows during the war anticipated trade patterns that became prevalent within the European Community in the 1960s.

SECTION VII

There remains the problem of determining the extent and motivations of Germany's disengagement from foreign trade under the regime of autarky policy. Intertemporal comparison shows that very strong terms of trade effects persisted. A terms of trade index calculated from the German trade statistics shows an increase of 31 per cent over the period from 1928 to 1938. Germany's imports consisted mainly of foodstuffs and raw materials, finished producers' and capital goods being its prime export commodity. Germany thus benefited from the spectacular collapse in the relative price of agrarian products and bulk commodities that manifested itself before and during the great depression, mainly to the detriment of US and British trade with Germany. Another equally marked effect results from Germany's policies of retaining parity with gold while blocking convertibility, which led to an artificial rise in nominal exchange rates. The country operated a highly sophisticated system of export promotion to compensate for the effect on export prices and the extent to which these subsidies are reflected in the data is not entirely clear. Data are shown in table 9. In nominal values, there was a high trade deficit in 1928. By 1938, these imbalances had disappeared almost entirely, and nominal trade values were drastically lower than in the 1920s. On a constant price basis, however, Germany's high trade deficits of the 1920s re-emerged again in the mid-1930s when similar levels of capacity utilization were reached. This evidence alone suggests that shortage of foreign exchange must have been the. major restriction shaping the German foreign exchange balance in the prewar years. There is also a regional aspect to substantiate this. Comparing the trade figures of 1938 with those of 1928, the share of the western powers in German imports is seen to have declined considerably (and it has been shown above that there was another sharp reduction in 1939). Again, the effect of this on real trade flows is potentially obscured by terms-of-trade effects. German trade statistics make it possible to obtain data at constant 1928 prices for individual countries by major items traded, which in this case represent between 60 and 70 per cent of the respective trade volume. In table 10, the results for this estimation of trade volume by country are shown for German trade with the US, Britain, and France. The real figures obtained for 1938 show that the much-celebrated autarky drive of the Nazi economy almost evaporates: once the dramatic reduction in Germany's trade with its most important creditors is controlled for, the decline in German foreign trade between 1928 and 1938 diminishes from almost 15 per cent to a mere 2.5 per cent. This is summarized in a fifth conclusion: German autarky policies in the 1930s were to a large extent a process of selective disengagement from trade with the US, Great Britain, and France. Imports from the rest of the world remained basically unchanged in comparison with their pre-depression peak. Still, however, the ratio of imports to national product was lower in 1938 than in 1928.

As a consequence, it seems that much of the prominent eastward move of German trade policies may be attributed to a composition effect. Hence it is mostly the consequences of Germany's default on debt for its trade with the major western countries which explain German autarky policies, rather than a deliberate programme of economic war preparation and the economic penetration of eastern Europe, as the older literature often had it. This result is further corroborated by the work of historians on German trade relations with Britain and the US during the 1930s. This line of research has pointed to the varying degree of success with which the Germans kept re-negotiating their debt obligations, often, but not always, offering to pay more if they were allowed to export more.

Table 9. Nominal and real trade volumes1938 and 1928 (RM million)

Nominal imports

1938

6,051.7

Nominal exports

1938

5,619.1

1928

14,001.3

1928

12,275.6

Rate of change

-56.8%

Rate of change

-54.2%

Prices of 1928

Real imports

1938

11,973.3

Real exports

1938

8,491.9

1928

14,001.3

1928

12,275.6

Rate of change

-14.5%

Rate of change

-30.8%

Implicit deflator

Implicit deflator

of imports 1938

50.5

of exports 1938

66.2

Source: Mitchell, European historical statistics.

C:\Users\Adina\Desktop\10.png



rev

Our Service Portfolio

jb

Want To Place An Order Quickly?

Then shoot us a message on Whatsapp, WeChat or Gmail. We are available 24/7 to assist you.

whatsapp

Do not panic, you are at the right place

jb

Visit Our essay writting help page to get all the details and guidence on availing our assiatance service.

Get 20% Discount, Now
£19 £14/ Per Page
14 days delivery time

Our writting assistance service is undoubtedly one of the most affordable writting assistance services and we have highly qualified professionls to help you with your work. So what are you waiting for, click below to order now.

Get An Instant Quote

ORDER TODAY!

Our experts are ready to assist you, call us to get a free quote or order now to get succeed in your academics writing.

Get a Free Quote Order Now